While we are all capable of identifying unfairness at a local level, i.e. the guy on the next desk is getting paid more than you for doing the same job, in economics more distant and general concepts of fairness are harder to pin down. In some ways, concepts of fairness do not sit comfortably within the subject of economics, as fairness is usually considered a moral judgment which has to be subjectively made by a person or group, whereas economics is the study of a mostly autonomous system which mechanically manages and responds to human economic needs and economic actions. Usually measures of fairness in economics have to resort to level playing field type concepts, which focus on fairness consisting of an absence of distortion or advantage, rather than being about equal outcomes. The famous right wing economist Friedrich Hayek did as much as any one to popularize these concepts, and in his book, Law Legislation and Liberty, he also has a take on why we crave fairness / social justice, and how this craving might even be dangerous!
Another famous right wing economist, Milton Freidman, in his book, Free to Choose also argues that it is competition and choice that are the best drivers of fairness in economic relations:
In economics, the labour market provides an incredibly complex instance where fairness issues get created and (kind of) resolved continuously. As Friedman tells us above, the main mode of resolution in the labour market is choice: if a person thinks he or she is underpaid they can change jobs. If an employer believes the same labour can be attained for less, they restructure, outsource or offshore. But the reference point for making these fairness judgements is the going market prices of the factors in question, not a higher concept of fairness. However, this free choice driven model of the labour market without qualification is in danger of being overly simplistic, and things get more complicated when one or both sides has sunken non-transferable costs into the relationship, or when one or both sides attains a monopoly strangle hold over the choice mechanism.
For example our current junior doctors dispute involves these monopoly and sunken cost issues in spades. The doctors have sunken years of hard study into their careers, and are at the mercy of a monopoly employer whom can change the relative attractiveness of their vocation at a stroke. Likewise, the doctors are capable of organizing to strike, knowing that their labour is particularly urgent and irreplaceable. To an economist, the debate becomes: are the government trying to capture the short term advantage of doctors having already sunken the costs of years of study, knowing they are unable to switch professions easily, or are the doctors stuck in a pre recession mindset, where wages are high and NHS spending generous? I stress that regarding this dispute, I do not know all the details and cannot answer as to what is fair. But it is possible none the less to take heed of the two giants of economics above and ask a couple of penetrating questions which could shed a bit of light on the issue:
I do not know the answers to these questions and have no opinion, but what the questions have in common is that they are trying to reveal the free choice mechanism from behind the sunken costs and monopoly issues that distort it. Again a concept of economic fairness has to defer to supply and demand concepts which have choice operating at their core, although now the choice factor is more theoretical in that we look for a one step removed proxy for it. There are some who may rail against these supply and demand concepts being employed by the dismal, cold hearted economists to settle such complex moral arguments, and there probably are other considerations important within the debate. … But challenge them for an alternative rational system of 'fairly' setting wage rates, and you quickly realise that deferring to these free choice concepts, although they are imperfect, are often the best guidance we can find to settle these kind of ongoing conflicts of interest.